Macroeconomics

GST Explainer: Value Added Tax 2.0

  • Blog Post Date 17 October, 2017
  • Perspectives
  • Print Page
Author Image

Aprajit Mahajan

University of California, Berkeley

aprajit@berkeley.edu

Author Image

Shekhar Mittal

University of California, Los Angeles

Shekhar.Mittal.1@anderson.ucla.edu

Aprajit Mahajan (UC Berkeley) and Shekhar Mittal (UCLA) outline some features of the GST that attempt to address the challenges of implementing a VAT system in India



The GST is a single nationally unified indirect tax and as such possesses all the advantages and disadvantages of a Value Added Tax (VAT)-type system in an emerging economy. In this article we first briefly outline the key advantages of a well-run VAT system and then describe some of the challenges faced in implementing a VAT system in India. Finally, we outline some features in the GST that attempt to address these challenges and provide some critical commentary.

A VAT primer

VAT adoption has grown rapidly over the past 50 years from just one country in 1960 to over 160 countries by 2015. VAT is attractive to policymakers because it generates a paper trail where each party’s report of a transaction can be cross-checked against its counter-party’s report. In particular, buyers have an incentive to report purchases since they receive tax credits based on such reports while sellers face a disincentive since reporting sales increases their tax liability. This opposed incentive is widely viewed as a key feature of the VAT that enables a tax authority to compare buyer and seller reports (referred to as third-party verification) and to thus reduce the likelihood of evasion.

Economists have noted that this self-enforcement mechanism can ‘unravel’ if a firm can under-report sales, in the sense that all the firms upstream (that is, further up in the VAT supply chain) from the under-reporting firm can now also collude in turn to under-report sales and reduce their tax liabilities. In well-developed VAT systems the under-reporting of sales typically only occurs at the end-node1 so that a relatively high degree of collusion all along the VAT chain is required to sustain evasion. On the other hand, as we note in recent work, much less collusion is needed to maintain evasion in an economy with a large number of unregistered firms (essentially since under-reporting can occur at all points in a VAT chain and not just at the end-point)2.

Another stated advantage of a VAT system in an emerging economy is that it provides incentives for formalisation and thereby broadens the tax base. The argument is that informal (unregistered) firms face pressures from their buyers to formalise so that the latter can claim tax credits on their purchases from the former. However, there is relatively little empirical evidence for this claim and it is unclear whether the GST will indeed achieve greater formalisation3.

The GST improves upon the patchwork of existing state-level VAT systems in at least two important ways: First, by unifying the VAT system nationally and in particular by making inter-state transactions visible to tax officials across states, the GST system removes tax loopholes that stemmed from the special treatment of inter-state transactions. Second, the GST improves upon the third-party verification systems currently in place in many states and this by itself should improve the tax regime and may improve collections. As always, the devil is in the details, and the extent to which these advantages are realised will depend in part upon how such a complex and technically demanding system is implemented in practice.

Placing inter- and intra-state trade on a common tax footing

Under the previous tax regime, inter-state transactions were treated differently from intra-state transactions. To begin with, inter-state transactions did not share a common tax jurisdiction so that VAT adjustments (for example, tax credits) were not feasible. Likewise, third-party verification was also not possible since states did not have access to each other’s firms’ tax returns. Second, inter-state transactions were then taxed at lower rates than intra-state ones and it is commonly held that this created an easily exploitable tax loophole4.

The GST improves upon both these limitations of the previous system. First, the creation of a common tax system (GST Network) means that tax-jurisdictions in all states will have access to firm tax-returns from other states. This will enable third-party verification of inter-state transactions as well -- buyer and seller reports can now be compared (this reconciliation is intended to be done electronically). Second, the GST also eliminates the differential taxation on inter- and intra-state transactions, thereby removing a glaring tax loophole.

Improving third-party verification capacity

Despite significant reliance on technology, the previous VAT system still required substantial manual effort from tax officials. For instance, resolving computer-detected mismatches (between buyer and seller reports) was a time-consuming process and required substantial officer-level intervention5.

The existence of fraudulent or ‘bogus’ firms is another significant challenge facing tax authorities in India’s VAT system. In its simplest form, firms reduce their tax liabilities by claiming credits for purchases from bogus firms −- fraudulent firms that are nevertheless registered with the tax authority. Bogus firms, in turn, would employ dilatory tactics with respect to filing their own returns and limited audit resources mean that identifying such firms in a timely manner is a challenging task6 7.

The GST attempts to address these third-party verification issues by placing the burden of compliance primarily on the seller. Under the old VAT regime, firms filed a single return every quarter8. Under GST, firms must file three returns a month (in a staggered fashion). Firms first report sales and then subsequently report purchases. The key innovation is that the tax authority uses the sales reports to pre-fill the corresponding purchase entries in the purchase report forms. Any addition or modification to this pre-populated list of purchases requires a substantial amount of effort on the firm’s part. This innovation eliminates some of the most glaring tax loopholes and evasion strategies thought to be common in the previous regime (for example, some of the bogus firm strategies).

The proposed GST thus improves upon the previously existing VAT systems in a number of ways. However, important challenges remain. For instance, the benefits outlined above require a robust IT infrastructure that can execute the required checks and analyses in a timely and accessible manner9. It is also important to recognise that complying with GST requires increased firm effort which needs to be balanced against the gains to the tax authority. There are also other issues (for example, the multiple rates rather than a uniform rate) that other experts have already discussed here so we omit a discussion here. Finally, it is important to allow researchers to rigorously study the GST to the fullest extent possible to allow for a comprehensive evaluation going forward.

Notes:

  1. That is, when selling to final consumers (from whom no cross-checking is feasible).
  2. In Mittal and Mahajan (2017) we observe that roughly three-quarters of all firms in our data report selling to unregistered firms. These sales cannot be cross-checked since unregistered firms do not file returns.
  3. For instance, De Paula and Scheinkman (2010) and Piggott and Whalley (2001) argue that the formalisation incentives of the VAT may be quite limited (and provide evidence from Brazil and Canada, respectively).
  4. Chapter 11 of the Economic Survey 2016-17 analyses data from the VAT inter-state invoices and highlights that “cross border exchanges between and within firms amount to at least 54 percent of GDP, implying that interstate trade is 1.7 times larger than international trade. This may be a consequence of the current system of indirect taxes which perversely favours interstate trade over intra-state trade, especially in the cases of final consumption items, exempted goods, or goods that are input tax credit ineligible. If true, the GST by ironing out these oddities may normalise interstate trade.”
  5. In Mittal and Mahajan (2017) we examine the effect of improved third-party verification on tax collections and find that the increases in tax revenue are concentrated among the very largest firms. This is potentially important in a context with limited audit resources and where the majority of firms do not deposit any tax.
  6. Firms would reduce their tax liability by claiming to make purchases from registered bogus firms, by having all the required paperwork in case they were investigated. However, the bogus firm would never file a tax return, or would file a tax return but never deposit the tax amount. In such cases, the tax administration would have to identify such bogus firms and then explicitly issue notices to the firms buying from such bogus firms and cancel their input credits. In many instances, this would result in long and costly litigations.
  7. There also appears to be substantial litigation around these cases, often with inconsistent judgements across cases.
  8. Different states had different requirements. But all purchases, sales and final calculations were filed in a single return.
  9. See, for example, https://scroll.in/article/850981/log-in-error-missing-data-multiple-deadlines-gst-is-tripping-up-on-technical-glitches for some early anecdotal evidence on the difficulties involved with the technical implementation.

Further Reading

  • Government of India (2017), ‘Economic Survey 2016-17’, Economic Division, Department of Economic Affairs, Ministry of Finance, January 2017.
  • Government of India (2017), ‘Union Budget 2017-18’, Ministry of Finance, 1 February 2017.
  • Mittal, Shekhar and Aprajit Mahajan (2017), “Vat in Emerging Economies: Does Third Party Verification Matter?”, SSRN Electronic Journal. Available here.
  • Paula, Áureo De, and José A Scheinkman (2010), “Value-Added Taxes, Chain Effects, and Informality”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2(4):195-221.
  • Piggott, John and John Whalley (2001), "VAT Base Broadening, Self Supply, and the Informal Sector”, American Economic Review, 91(4):1084-1094.
Tags:
No comments yet
Join the conversation
Captcha Captcha Reload

Comments will be held for moderation. Your contact information will not be made public.

Related content

Sign up to our newsletter