Macroeconomics

Monetary policy in India and other developing countries

  • Blog Post Date 03 September, 2012
  • Articles
  • Print Page

Setting interest rates and controlling inflation is an altogether different challenge in countries like India. This column argues that in many developing countries, the financial system is still too underdeveloped for monetary policy to have a reliable effect on the economy, raising doubts over several of today’s policies.


It is perhaps worth stressing the point: policymaking in developing countries is an altogether different challenge – and monetary policy is no exception. The assumptions underlying monetary transmission in advanced countries – that is, how the central bank’s interest rate filters through the economy – cannot be applied mechanically to developing economies. The conventional way of looking at monetary transmission focuses on the effects of central bank actions on:

  • short-term and long-term interest rates on domestic securities (the short- and long-term interest rate channels),
  • bank lending rates and loan avaliability (the bank lending channel),
  • equity and real estate prices (the asset channel), and
  • the exchange rate (the exchange rate channel).

These effects are created through effective arbitrage along several margins: between different domestic short-term securities, between domestic short-term and long-term securities, between long-term securities and equities, between domestic and foreign securities, and between domestic financial and real assets. But these margins need an economy with a highly developed and competitive financial system in order to be effective.That includes: a strong institutional environment, so that loan contracts are protected and financial intermediation is conducted through formal financial markets; an independent central bank; a well-functioning and highly liquid interbank market for reserves; a well-functioning and highly liquid secondary market for government securities with a broad range of maturities; aell-functioning and highly liquid markets for equities and real estate; a high degree of international capital mobility; and a floating exchange rate. These features are typically taken for granted in the OECD but the same assumptons cannot be made for developing countires.

We expect monetary transmission to be different in a developing country context from what we are familiar with in industrial countries.Indeed, as argued in our recent research with Antonio Spilimbergo (Mishra et al. 2012), at first sight there are strong reasons for believing that the monetary transmission mechanism in developing countries is fundamentally different from that described above.

  • short-term and long-term interest rates on domestic securities (the short- and long-term interest rate channels),
  • First, the complete absence or poor development of domestic securities markets suggests that both the short-run and long-run interest rate channels will be weak.
  • Second, small and illiquid markets for assets such as equities and real estate will tend to weaken the asset channel.
  • Third, in countries that are imperfectly integrated with international financial markets and tend to maintain relatively fixed exchange rates, the exchange rate channel will tend to be completely absent, or relatively weak.

In general, therefore, the financial structure of developing countries should lead us to expect the interest rate, asset, and exchange rate channels to be weak or non-existent in such countries.

The importance of bank lending

By a process of elimination, then, the bank lending channel seems to be the most viable general mode for monetary transmission. The strength and reliability of this channel, however, depends on several characteristics of the domestic economy.

The conditions needed for strengthening the bank-lending channels are not likely to hold in developing countries. The relevant properties of the bank lending channel concern two links in the causal chain from monetary policy actions to overall (aggregate) demand–that between monetary policy actions and the availability and cost of bank credit, and that between the availability and cost of bank credit and aggregate demand. When the formal financial sector is small, as is true in the vast majority of developing countries, the second of these links is likely to be weak. But the link between monetary policy actions and the availability and cost of bank credit may well be weak as well. Specifically, the academic literature suggests that it may be undermined by two factors:

  • If the banking industry is non-competitive, changes in banks’ costs of funds may be reflected in bank profit margins, rather than in the supply of bank lending.
  • If a poor institutional environment increases the cost of bank lending, banks may conduct lending activity in a manner that weakens the effects of monetary policy actions on the supply of loans by using reserves as a buffer to sustain their lending to low-cost customers when the central bank tightens credit conditions and to avoid lending to high-cost customers when the central bank loosens credit conditions.

Lack of strength and reliability

We examine broad cross-country differences in the links between central bank policy actions and bank lending rates in advanced, emerging, and low-income economies (LICs). We focus on the association between central bank policy rates and money market rates, as well as that between money market rates and bank lending rates. In doing so, we seek to unearth suggestive empirical regularities, rather than to identify specific causal relationships. We find a much weaker link between the policy instrument (central bank interest rates) and money market rates in poorer economies than for advanced and emerging economies, both in the short and in the long run. We find a similar result for the link between money market rates and bank lending rates in the short term, and while differences in long-term effects are not as pronounced, they remain weaker in low-income countries. Most importantly, changes in money-market rates explain a much smaller proportion of the variance in bank lending rates in low-income countries than in either advanced or emerging economies.

Facts on the ground

There is a large empirical literature examining the effects of monetary policy innovations (as measured through a variety of monetary policy variables including, but not limited to, policy interest rates) on aggregate demand (as indicated by the behaviour of output and/or prices) in a large number of individual developing economies. In our joint study (Mishra and Montiel, 2012), we conclude that it is very hard to come away from our review of the evidence with much confidence in the strength of monetary transmission in developing countries. We fail to uncover any instances in which more than one careful study confirmed results for the effects of monetary shocks on aggregate demand that are similar to the effects in the US or other advanced countries. The question is how to interpret this state of affairs. As suggested by Égert and Macdonald (2009) (for the case of transition economies in central and Eastern Europe), it is likely to reflect some combination of the ‘facts on the ground’ and shortcomings in the empirical methods that have been applied to understanding this issue.

We suspect, however, that ‘facts on the ground’ may indeed be an important part of the story. The failure of a wide range of empirical approaches to yield consistent and convincing evidence of effective monetary transmission in developing countries, and the fact that the strongest evidence for effective monetary transmission has arisen for relatively prosperous and more institutionally-developed countries such as some Central and Eastern European transition economies (at least in the later stages of their transition) and countries such as Morocco and Tunisia, make us doubt whether methodological shortcomings are the whole story.

The need to think differently

We interpret the evidence presented in our research, as well as that of the broader literature, as creating a strong presumption that in the financial environment that tends to characterise many developing economies, monetary policy is likely to have both weak and unreliable effects on aggregate demand. If this is true, the stabilisation challenge in developing countries is acute indeed, and identifying the means of enhancing the effectiveness of monetary policy in such countries is an important challenge for policymakers and researchers alike.

When domestic monetary policy is weak and unreliable, activist policy is less desirable, and the adoption of policy regimes that raise the stakes associated with attaining publicly-announced monetary objectives, such as a target rate of inflation, should be postponed or their design should be modified to take the uncertainty about monetary policy effects into account. In addition, weak and unreliable monetary transmission weakens the arguments for floating exchange rates as well as for capital account restrictions under fixed exchange rates.

Further reading

  • Mishra Prachi, Peter Montiel, and Antonio Spilimbergo (2012), “Monetary Transmission in Low-Income Countries: Effectiveness and Policy Implications”, IMF Working Paper No. 10/223, IMF Economic Review, 60(2).
  • Mishra Prachi and Peter Montiel (2012), “How Effective Is Monetary Transmission in Low-Income Countries? A Survey of the Empirical Evidence”, IMF WP No. 12/143.
  • Égert, Balázs and Ronald MacDonald (2009), "Monetary Transmission Mechanism in Central and Eastern Europe: Surveying the Surveyable",Journal of Economic Surveys, 23(2):277-327.
Tags:
No comments yet
Join the conversation
Captcha Captcha Reload

Comments will be held for moderation. Your contact information will not be made public.

Related content

Sign up to our newsletter