Money & Finance

Estimating losses to consumers due to mis-sold life insurance policies

  • Blog Post Date 19 February, 2014
  • Articles
  • Print Page
Author Image

Monika Halan

National Institute of Securities Markets

dhanchakra21@gmail.com

Author Image

Renuka Sane

National Institute of Public Finance and Policy

renuka.sane@nipfp.org.in

Mis-selling of financial products has prompted regulators in India to work on consumer protection in financial markets. However, evidence on actual mechanisms and extent of mis-selling is lacking. This column estimates losses to consumers owing to mis-selling of Unit Linked Insurance Products in India between 2004-2005 and 2009-2010 – one of the biggest episodes of malpractice in the country’s finance sector.

In theory, the first port of call for resolving problems of mis-selling in the marketplace is information disclosure coupled with competition. This assumes that consumers are rational, have access to information and can process this information (Zingales 2009). In recent decades, academic evidence has shown that there are many problems with this framework, particularly in the context of financial markets.

Competition in financial markets can rapidly drive up the complexity of financial products and services, and consumers have limited capability and incentive to gather information and process it. Gabaix and Laibson (2006) show that it is optimal for a firm to "shroud" or hide fees1 when the market has at least some myopic investors, and that in such markets, competition does not ensure products at the lowest cost, or optimal service for the consumer. Further, when consumers with limited understanding are juxtaposed with sales agents and distributors who are incentivised by remuneration structures to push financial products regardless of their suitability for the consumer, this can lead to rampant mis-selling (Inderst and Ottaviani 2009).

Consumer protection in financial markets

These market failures have motivated interest among financial regulators worldwide on constructing specialised mechanisms for consumer protection in finance. Prominent examples are the ‘Future of Financial Advice’ programme in 2013 in Australia, and the decision by the UK Financial Services Authority (FSA) in 2013 to ban upfront commissions for the sale of investment products.

The knowledge of consumers in emerging markets is inferior. A strong legal system provides protection against fraud and consumer abuse, but in emerging markets, weaknesses of laws, courts and enforcement yield reduced protection through conventional channels. This yields an environment with losses to consumers, a general mistrust of finance, and low financial inclusion. Hence, the issues of consumer protection in finance in India are more important when compared with advanced economies.

Financial regulators in India have started working on consumer protection. Upfront, charging commissions on selling mutual funds was banned in 2009. Commission caps have been tightened on some insurance products. The draft Indian Financial Code (IFC) that was created by the Financial Sector Legislative Reforms Commission (FSLRC) in 2013 breaks new ground in putting consumer protection at the heart of financial regulation.

The debates in India, however, are hampered by a lack of strong evidence. Little is known about the actual mechanisms and extent of mis-selling. A related issue is that of disgorgement, wherein the government forces financial firms to repay consumers for the losses incurred by them owing to mis-selling. An example is the FSA of UK getting banks to disgorge more than £10 billion to compensate for mi-sold ‘Payment Protection Insurance’, as of December 2013. Disgorgement is fair in the eyes of consumers, and can induce better deterrence, but it requires accurate estimation of losses.

In a recent paper, we attempt to quantify losses of consumers in one clearly identified episode of mis-selling over a five-year period between 2004-2005 to 2009-2010, associated with Unit Linked Insurance Products (ULIPs) (Halan, Sane and Thomas 2013).

Mis-selling of ULIPs in India

ULIPs were investment products that were introduced in 2001 by the insurance industry. Consumers were told that they were buying a three-year money doubling product that also gave them some life insurance cover and a tax break. Consumers needed to steadily put money into the policy every year, for a period of at least 10 to 15 years, in order to accrue benefits from it. However, the sales pitch was verbal and sellers promised doubling of money in three years. Anecdotal evidence suggests that distributors did not inform investors that ULIP policies needed to be funded every year for at least 10 years, but that product life tenure can be 20-25 years as well2 .for returns to be obtained. The ULIP was not a three-year tenure product, but had a lock-in for three years after which consumers could withdraw their money. The sales pitch made product lock-in look like product tenure.

Sales agents were paid as much as 40% of the first contribution by the consumers. This gave sales agents a strong incentive to sell the product. Regulations allowed insurance companies to keep the entire value of the policy if it was surrendered within three years. This made insurance companies strong beneficiaries if the consumer stopped making contributions into the policy after initiation. In this environment, there were incentives to get a consumer started on a ULIP and then fail to follow through with contributions every year for 10 to 15 years.

The profits obtained by insurance companies and by sales agents of ULIPs gave them a strong incentive to promote ULIPs at the expense of other insurance policies and other investment products. This began in 2004-2005, and by 2007-2008, a full 75% of the premiums that went into insurance companies came from ULIPs.

Estimating losses

We use two approaches that use publicly available data to estimate the loss to investors from mis-selling of insurance products. The first approach uses the number of lapsed policies from annual reports of the insurance regulator - Insurance Regulatory and Development Authority (IRDA), while the second method uses the persistence of premium payments that are reported in annual reports of individual insurance companies.

The first method captures the loss in renewal premiums, which are the premiums paid each year to renew the policy. When the policy is bought, the premium is called the first year premium, and the subsequent premiums over the lifetime of the policy are called renewal premiums. If subsequent premiums are not paid3 for reasons other than death or income shock, the policy is said to be mis-sold. The total of such premiums then is the loss to policyholders due to mis-selling. This is called the ‘renewal premium method’.

The second method is called the ‘persistency method’, which tracks the performance of the premium flows over the first five years of the policy tenure. A policy is said to have a ‘good’ persistency record if the premiums are renewed each year. A policy is said to have ‘poor’ persistency if the premiums stop after one or more years. The regulator tracks this data over 13th, 25th, 37th, 49th and 61st month intervals.

The underlying assumption in both these methods is that when policies lapse for reasons other than death or financial emergencies, it is because the consumer discovers that the policy is unsuitable, treats the lapsed premium as sunk cost4, and abandons the policy from his investment portfolio. This assumption is validated by insurance actuaries who estimate that 80% of the lapsed premium is due to mis-sold policies5, and from several consumer interviews conducted by the Swarup Committee on Investor Awareness and Protection constituted by the Government of India in 2009.

Both methods show that investors lost Rs. 1.5 trillion ($28 billion approx.) during the period that was studied, on account of mis-sold policies. This makes it one of the biggest episodes of malpractice in Indian finance, ever.

Implications for policy

Financial regulators in India need to move towards a disgorgement philosophy, where consumers are reimbursed for the misdeeds of financial firms. From the viewpoint of social welfare, the overall cost to society exceeds the losses of consumers, when all the distortions are taken into account - for example, the mis-allocation of human resources into making, advertising and selling ULIPs. However, a founding legal principle should be to identify direct losers and reimburse them to the extent possible. This study is a first attempt at quantifying losses to consumers.

Our study is one element of an emerging literature on household finance in India (Anagol and Kim 2012, Anagol, Cole and Sarkar 2012, Campbell, Ramadorai and Ranish 2012, Anagol et al. 2013). This literature has substantial implications for the structure of laws, regulatory agencies and enforcement mechanisms pertaining to consumer protection in financial markets. Government intervention in financial markets must avoid centralised planning, and focus on market failures. This requires an intellectual framework that identifies and measures market failures in finance.

Notes:

  1. In this context, fees refer to the total cost to the consumer. For example, a consumer may pay Rs.1000 as premium. 40% of the Rs.1000 is actually paid to the sales agent as commissions, and only the remaining 60% is invested. The actual amount of commissions paid is not made explicit, and is thus hidden from the consumer.
  2. This means that it can 20-25 years for the consumer to obtain returns from the product.
  3. If the policy holder pays the first premium and then not the second (or third), he loses his entire first (and second) premium. After the third premium, from year four, if he does not pay the fourth premium, he gets the value left in the policy. Due to the high commissions paid out from the policy in the first three years, the value is a fraction of what he has paid.
  4. Sunk cost is a cost that has already been incurred and cannot be recovered.
  5. See Halan et al. (2013) for more details.

Further Reading

  • Anagol, Santosh and Hugh Hoikwang Kim (2012), “The Impact of Shrouded Fees: Evidence from a Natural Experiment in the Indian Mutual Funds Market”, American Economic Review, 102(1), 576–93.
  • Anagol, Santosh, Shawn Cole and Shayak Sarkar (2012), ‘Understanding the Incentives of Commissions Motivated Agents: Theory and Evidence from the Indian Life Insurance Market’, Working Paper 12-055, Harvard Business School.
  • Anagol, Santosh, Vijaya Marisetty, Renuka Sane and Buvaneshwaran Venugopal (2013), ‘Distribution fees and mutual fund flows: Evidence from a natural experiment in the Indian mutual funds market’, Discussion Paper WP-2013-004, IGIDR.
  • Campbell, John Y., Tarun Ramadorai and Benjamin Ranish (2012), ‘How do regulators influence mortgage risk? Evidence from an emerging market’, Discussion Paper 18394, NBER Working Paper.
  • Gabaix, X. and D. Laibson (2006), “Shrouded Attributes, Consumer Myopia and Information Suppression in Competitive Markets”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121, 505–540.
  • Halan, Monika, Renuka Sane and Susan Thomas (2012), ‘The case of the missing billions: Estimating losses to customers due to mis-sold life insurance policies’, IGIDR Working paper, WP-2013-007.
  • Inderst, Roman and Marco Ottaviani (2009), “Misselling through Agents”, American Economic Review, 99(3), 883–908.
  • Srikrishna, Justice B. N. (2013), ‘Financial Sector Legislative Reforms Commission: Vol. I and II’, Ministry of Finance.
  • Gabaix, X. and D. Laibson (2006), “Shrouded Attributes, Consumer Myopia and Information Suppression in Competitive Markets”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121, 505–540.
No comments yet
Join the conversation
Captcha Captcha Reload

Comments will be held for moderation. Your contact information will not be made public.

Related content

Sign up to our newsletter